CONTINENTAL DRIFT
2 0 0 8 < back  
The Ground*


Glossary

{ Autonomy } { Fictitious Commodity } { Overaccumulation Crisis }
{ Creative Destruction } { Latin American } { Risk Society }
{ Culture of Capital } { Consensus } { Subjective Cartography }
{ Dialogicity } { Military-Economic Bifurcation } { Unintended Social Order }
{ Double Movement } { Neoconservative Morality } { Zombie Category }
{ East Asian Network } { Neoliberal Governmentality }  
{ Extradisciplinary Investigation } { Non-State Public Sphere }  

 

 

 

 

 



__________________________________
Autonomy

As a germ, autonomy emerges when explicit and unlimited interrogation explodes on the scene – an interrogation that has bearing not on the “facts” but on the social imaginary significations and their possible grounding. This is a moment of creation, and it ushers in a new type of society and a new type of individuals. I am speaking intentionally of germ, for autonomy, social as well as individual, is a project. The rise of unlimited interrogation creates a new social-historical eidos: reflectiveness in the full sense, self-reflectiveness, as well as the individual and the institutions which embody it. The questions raised are, on the social level: Are our laws good? Are they just? Which laws ought we to make? And, on the individual level: Is what I think true? Can I know if it is true – and if so, how?...
Autonomy comes from autos-nomos: (to give to) oneself one's laws... Autonomy does not consist in acting according to a law discovered in an immutable reason and discovered once and for all. It is the unlimited self-questioning about the law and its foundations and the capacity, in light of this interrogation, to make, to do, and to institute (and therefore also, to say). Autonomy is the reflective capacity of a reason creating itself in an endless movement, both as individual and social reason...
If the autonomous society is that society which self-institutes itself explicitly and lucidly, the one that knows that it itself posits its institutions and its significations, this means that it knows as well that they have no source other than its own instituting and signification-giving activity, no extrasocial guarantee. We thereby encounter once again the radical problem of democracy. Democracy, when it is true democracy, is the regime that explicitly renounces all ultimate guarantees and knows no limitations other than its self-limitation...
This amounts to saying that democracy is the only tragic political regime – it is the only regime that takes risks, that faces openly the possibility of its self-destruction.
Cornelius Castoriadis, “Power, Politics, Autonomy” and “The Logic of Magmas and the Question of Autonomy,” both in The Castoriadis Reader (Oxford UP, 1991), pp. 163-63 and 316.

top


__________________________________
Creative Destruction

Marx emphasizes how a persistent and generalized fall in the rate of profit transforms inter-capitalist competition from a positive-sum game – in which capitals benefit from one another’s expansion – into a zero-sum (or even a negative-sum) game – that is, into “cutthroat competition”... The fall in the rate of profit and the intensification of the competitive struggle, however, do not end in a stationary state. On the contrary, they lead to the destruction of the social framework in which accumulation is embedded and to the creation of a new one. In Marx’s account, this creative destruction takes three main forms: an increase in the size of capitals and the reorganization of business enterprise; the formation of surplus population and a new international division of labor; and the emergence of new and larger centers of capital accumulation...
Marx draws a distinction between concentration of capital – the increase in size of individual capitals arising from accumulation – and centralization of capital, which transforms “many small into few large capitals”... The centralization and reorganization of capital go hand in hand with the formation of a reserve army of labor and a reorganization of the international division of labor. The extension and speed-up of technological and organizational change strengthens the capital-intensive and labor-saving bias of capitalist development, generating a “relatively redundant population of laborers”... This surplus population is then available for new rounds of capitalist development on an ever increasing scale...
Schumpeter’s analysis of capitalism’s creative destruction covers only a small part of Marx’s ground but has the advantage of highlighting key insights... He divides the incessant working of the process of creative destruction into two phases: the phase of revolution proper and the phase of absorption of the results of the revolution: “While these things are being initiated we have brisk expenditure and predominating ‘prosperity’... and while they are being completed and their results pour forth we have the elimination of antiquated elements of the industrial structure and predominating ‘depression.’” In Schumpeter’s representation, profit-oriented innovations (and their impact on competitive pressures) cluster in time. However, it is just as plausible to hypothesize that they also cluster in space. We can then substitute “where” for “while” in the above quotation and read it as a description of a spatial polarization of zones of predominating “prosperity” and zones of predominating “depression.”
Schumpeter’s conception of creative destruction has the further advantage of defining the innovations that underlie the process very broadly, as “the carrying out of new combinations.” These include, not just technological and organizational innovations in industry, but all commercial innovations – such as the opening up of a new market, a new trading route, a new source of supply, the marketing of a new product, or the introduction of a new organization in the procurement and distribution of merchandise – which succeed in “leading” the economy into new channels. Shumpeter calls the agents of this leadership “entrepreneurs” – individuals who may or may not be “capitalists,” in the sense of having substantial command over means of production and payment, but who have the capacity to detect and seize the opportunities for excess profits that can be reaped through a rerouting of the established flow of economic life.
Giovanni Arrighi, Adam Smith in Beijing: Lineages of the 21st Century (London: Verso, 2007), pp. 82-88.

top


__________________________________
Culture of Capital

The first culture of capitalism is the one that everyone knows about. It developed in the secular culture of the Renaissance, used the visual forms and literary narratives of antiquity as its raw material, and had naturalistic illusionism as its goal. If it tended to swing between the poles of neo-classicism and anecdotal realism, that was also the source of its enduring strength. It survived not just the transition to industrial capitalism, but also the convulsive politics of industrialism in nineteenth and early twentieth-century Europe. This last claim needs some justification, for this is the point at which the first culture is often said to have broken down. But the period from 1850 to 1950 conforms, in significant respects, to the pre-existing pattern: nineteenth-century realism was the last, and perhaps also the fullest expression of the classical aesthetic of mimesis; the first half of the twentieth century saw the final flourishing of the classical style...
The second culture of capitalism is equally familiar, but not everyone thinks it is a civilization. Before the 1970s it was called mass culture or kitsch; since then it has been known, misleadingly, as postmodernism. It can be argued that the continuity between kitsch and postmodernism is such that they constitute a single culture; and that this culture replaced not, as the word ‘postmodernism’ implies, modernism, but classicism. The differences between the first and second cultures of capitalism might be enumerated as follows: 1) the shift from mimesis to the meme; from the imitation of the world to the reproduction of the unit of reproduction – or, to put it another way, from iconocity to indexicality; and, following from this, 2) the acceptance of stylistic eclecticism (classical models enjoyed their unique prestige on account of their supposed naturalism, their occasional use as ornament in architectural postmodernism was deeply anti-classical), 3) the reliance on large numbers of consumers to distribute/create the product, and 4) the erasure of the social rather than the technical traces of facture.
The preconditions of commodity culture (as I shall call it) were the expansion of the market and the development of new media. What poetry and painting were for classical culture, the periodical, the photograph and their progeny (film, radio, TV, video, other electronic media) were for the culture of commodities. The sources of commodity culture were various: sometimes (as with popular music) drawing almost exclusively on folk traditions; at others using the classical, sometimes viewed through the prism of modernism. The so-called postmodern era has been characterized not by any fundamental change in commodity culture, but by its colonization of the institutions and media of classicism...
By simultaneously resisting and mediating the two cultures modernism created a space between them, a distinct zone where their transgressive intermingling did not instantly compromise their separation. This liminal space facilitated the long overlap between the two cultures; it was also the route through which one culture turned into the other. If the space of modernism is the space between the cultures of capitalism, and the time of modernism is that of their overlapping, the trajectory of modernism is that which leads from the first to the second. We can picture this trajectory as a double fold. Modernism begins where classicism turns back on itself, and ends where it turns back into commodity culture.
Malcom Bull, “Between the Cultures of Capital,” New Left Review 11, 2001, pp. 98-103.

top


__________________________________
Dialogicity

The word in the dialogical relation as understood by Bakhtin is never a neutral word of the language, devoid of intentions, uninhabited by the voices of others. The speaker first receives the speech of others (starting from the voice of the mother), with all its intonations, its emotional affirmations. My own expressiveness finds every word already inhabited by the expressiveness of the other. To speak is to enter into a dialogical relation with the words of others, not initially with the meaning of the words, but with the expressions, the intonations and the voices. Speaking means appropriating the speech of the other. Speaking, as Bakhtin says, is like opening a path through the word itself, which is a multiplicity full of the voices, the intonations, the desires of others.
To whom does the word belong? To me, to others, to no one? Can I be the owner of a common good, like the word, in the same way as I can be the owner of an object?
“A word (or in general any sign) is interindividual. Everything that is said, expressed, is located outside the soul of the speaker and does not belong only to him. The word cannot be assigned to a single speaker. The author (speaker) has his own inalienable right to the word, but the listener has his rights, and those whose voices are heard in the word before the author comes upon it also have their rights” (Mikhail Bakhtin, Speech Genres and Other Late Essays, pp. 121-22).
Rimbaud’s formula, Je est un autre, should be understood as being present first of all in the words that constitute the tissue of our subjectivity. In my own words resound all the voices that have appropriated those words throughout history, but also all the future voices that will take them up again. The other is not only present in the already uttered word, but is an immanent and constituent element of every utterance still to come. For Bakhtin, the other and her words are possible worlds: consequently, the relation with the words of others is always the event of an encounter, and not a simple (linguistic) exchange or a (intersubjective) recognition...
The event created and managed by the TV or the media doesn’t open up any possibility, but constitutes the departure-point for an authoritarian production of meaning. It tries to form a subject of enunciation on which all statements will depend; to construct a point of origin for the slogans that will constitute a consensual, majority public. This departure-point or origin of meaning is “performed” by exploiting and neutralizing the creative functions which, in film, radio, television and the net, no longer necessarily involve an author (and his copyrights). These creative functions are recodified onto the individual subject and his modes of communication and expression: “At the very moment when writing and thinking were beginning to abandon the authorial function, it was taken up again by radio, TV and journalism” (Gilles Deleuze).
The power of financial centralization and the technological monopoly imposed on the articulations of expression serve to recreate the authorial function as a point of departure or origin for marketing, news, advertising, viewing publics, etc. The control societies integrate and channel the power to express and constitute multiplicity by separating it from its own capacity to create and propagate possibilities. This is the form that capitalist expropriation takes today.
Maurizio Lazzarato, “Expression versus communication,” Les révolutions du capitalisme (Paris: Les empêcheurs de penser en rond, 2004), pp. 159-60, 174-75.

top


__________________________________
Double Movement

For a century the dynamics of modern society was governed by a double movement: the market expanded continuously but this movement was met by a countermovement checking the expansion in definite directions. Vital though such a countermovement was for the protection of society, in the last analysis it was incompatible with the self-regulation of the market, and thus with the market system itself.
That system developed in leaps and bounds; it engulfed space and time, and by creating bank money it produced a dynamic hitherto unknown. By the time it reached its maximum extent, around 1914, every part of the globe, all its inhabitants and yet unborn generations, physical persons as well as huge fictitious bodies called corporations, were comprised in it. A new way of life spread over the planet with a claim to universality unparalleled since the age when Christianity started out on its career, only this time the movement was on a purely material level.
Yet simultaneously a countermovement was on foot. This was more than the usual defensive behavior of society faced with change; it was a reaction against a dislocation which attacked the fabric of society, and which would have destroyed the very organization of production that the market had called into being...
[The double movement] can be personified as the action of two organizing principles in society, each of them setting itself specific institutional aims, having the support of definite social forces and using its own distinctive methods. The one was the principle of economic liberalism, aiming at the establishment of a self-regulating market, relying on the support of the trading classes, and using largely laissez-faire and free trade as its methods; the other was the principle of social protection aiming at the conservation of man and nature as well as productive organization, relying on the varying support of those most immediately affected by the deleterious action of the market – primarily, but not exclusively, the working and the landed classes – and using protective legislation, restrictive association, and other instruments of intervention as its methods.
The middle [or trading] classes were the bearers of the nascent market economy; their business interests ran, on the whole, parallel to the general interest in regard to production and employment... On the other hand, the trading classes had no organ to sense the dangers involved in the exploitation of the physical strength of the worker, the destruction of family life, the devastation of neighborhoods, the denudation of forests, the pollution of rivers, the deterioration of craft standards, the disruption of folkways, and the general degradation of existence including housing and arts, as well as the innumerable forms of private and public life that do not affect profits.
By the turn of the nineteenth century – universal suffrage was now fairly general – the working class was an influential factor in the state; the trading classes, on the other hand, whose sway over the legislature was no longer unchallenged, became conscious of the political power involved in their leadership over industry. This peculiar localization of influence and power caused no trouble as long as the market system continued to function without great stress and strain; but when, for inherent reasons, this was no longer the case, and when tensions between the social classes developed, society itself was endangered by the fact that the contending parties were making government and business, state and industry, respectively, their strongholds. Two vital functions of society, the political and the economic, were being used and abused as weapons in a struggle for sectional interests. It was out of such a perilous deadlock that in the twentieth century the fascist crisis sprang.
Karl Polanyi, The Great Transformation (Boston: Beacon, 1945/2001), chapter 11, “Man Nature and Productive Organization.”

top


__________________________________
East Asian Network

Historically, there existed several maritime regions that stretched from Northeast Asia to East Asia and then from Southeast Asia to Oceania... This series of seas... includes the seas of Okhotsk and Japan, the Yellow Sea, the East China Sea, the South China Sea, the Java Sea, the Banda Sea, the Arafura Sea just north of Australia, the Coral Sea and the Tasman Sea between southeast Australia and New Zealand. Maritime Asia is far larger, at least as complex, and much more diverse than the Mediterranean. The landmasses separating the seas are thus separated from one another and have their own histories. The states, regions, and cities located along the periphery of each sea zone are close enough to influence one another but too far apart to be assimilated into a larger entity. Autonomy in this sense formed a major condition for the establishment of the looser form of political organization known as the tributary system.
Takeshi Hamashita, “The Intra-Regional System in East Asia,” in P. Ketzenstein and T. Shiraishi, eds., Network Power: Japan and Asia (Ithaca: Cornell U.P., 1997), p. 115.

In general, informal cooperation in East Asia has been based on three yuan (special relationships): ethnic ties, industrial linkages and geographical proximity. All three types of informal integration share several features. They are all 1) Market driven. Whatever the linkages are, it is the economic returns that ultimately lead to the formation of the informal integration. Other factors only facilitate the integration. This is different from formal integration, where many decisions are politics-driven. 2) Privately sponsored. In all cases of informal integration, the actual integrative activities have been conducted by private firms. 3) Network based. East Asia is a region where intergovernmental cooperation has been lacking. But privately, all kinds of networks have developed among Asians in different countries. At the macrolevel, there are production networks and ethnic business networks. At the micro-level, these two major networks consist of numerous networks formed through long-term corporate ties, (real or imaginary) kinship, voluntary organizations, etc. 4) Non-institutional. Integration through the informal mechanisms does not rely on formal international organizations. In many cases it is even non-contractual. Therefore informal integration involves much lower transaction costs than formal cooperation and is much easier to materialize.
Dajin Peng, "The changing nature of East Asia as an economic region," Pacific Affairs, Summer 2000.

China is the world’s second largest importer of oil, over half of which transits through the Straits of Malacca. China also currently consumes half of the world’s cement, a third of its steel, a quarter of its copper and a fifth of its aluminum – much of it traveling through chokepoints in the Straits of Malacca, Sunda, Lombok and Makassar. These geopolitical concerns, combined with China’s insatiable appetite for energy and natural resources, have made it inevitable that China, in its own way, should pick up where the United States left off. Just as regional economic forums that include the US, such as the Asia-Pacific Economic Forum (APEC), are losing steam, ASEAN-plus-3 [the Association of South-East Asian Nations, plus China, Japan and South Korea] has picked up momentum, and it is the latter that is calling important – and effective – economic shots for the region. And it is not at all unrealistic to anticipate the formation of the ASEAN-China Free Trade Area (ACFTA) in the near future. China is also gearing up to create a new security forum within the overall structure of the Asian Regional Forum (ARF), as an alternative to the series of bilateral security arrangements that the United States maintains.
Meredith Jung-En Woo, “The New East Asia,” in New Left Review 47, 2007.

top


__________________________________
Extradisciplinary Investigation

What is the logic, the need or the desire that pushes more and more artists to work outside the limits of their own discipline? Pop art, conceptual art, body art, performance and video each marked a rupture of the disciplinary frame. But these dramatized outbursts merely imported themes, media or expressive techniques back into what Yves Klein had termed the “specialized” ambiance of the gallery or the museum. Now we are confronted with a new series of outbursts, under such names as net.art, bio art, visual geography, space art and database art – to which one could add an archi-art, or art of architecture, as well as a machine art that reaches all the way back to 1920s constructivism. The heterogeneous character of the list suggests its application to all the domains where theory and practice meet. In the artistic forms that result, one still finds remains of the old modernist tropism whereby art designates itself first of all, drawing the attention back to its own operations of expression, representation, metaphorization or deconstruction. But there is something more at stake: a new tropism and a new sort of reflexivity, involving artists as well as theorists and activists in a passage beyond the limits traditionally assigned to their practice. The word tropism conveys the desire or need to turn towards something else, towards an exterior field or discipline; while the notion of reflexivity now indicates a critical return to the departure point, an attempt to transform the initial discipline, to end its isolation, to open up new possibilities of expression, analysis, cooperation and commitment. This back-and-forth movement, or rather, this transformative spiral, is the operative principle of extradisciplinary investigations.
The extradisciplinary ambition is to carry out rigorous investigations on terrains as far away from art as finance, biotech, geography, urbanism, psychiatry, the electromagnetic spectrum, etc., to bring forth on those terrains the “free play of the faculties” and the intersubjective experimentation that are characteristic of modern art, but also to try to identify, inside those same domains, the spectacular or instrumental uses so often made of the subversive liberty of aesthetic play. This complex movement, which never neglects the existence of the different disciplines, but never lets itself be trapped by them either, can provide a new departure point for what used to be called institutional critique.
The notion of transversality, developed by the practitioners of institutional analysis, helps to theorize the assemblages that link actors and resources from the art circuit to projects and experiments that don’t exhaust themselves inside it, but rather, extend elsewhere. These projects are based on a circulation between disciplines, often involving the real critical reserve of marginal or counter-cultural positions: social movements, political associations, squats, autonomous universities.
Brian Holmes, “Extradisciplinary Investigations” (2007), in Transversal, “Do you remember institutional critique?” (http://transform.eipcp.net/transversal/0106/holmes/en).

top


__________________________________
Fictitious Commodity

A fictitious commodity is something that has the form of a commodity (in other words, that can be bought and sold) but is not itself created in a profit-oriented labor process subject to the typical competitive pressures of market forces to rationalize its production and reduce the turnover time of invested capital. There are four key categories of fictitious commodity: land (or nature), money, knowledge and labor-power. Each is often treated as a simple factor of production, obscuring the conditions under which it enters the market economy, gets transformed therein, and so contributes to the production of goods and services for sale.
Land comprises all natural endowments (whether located on, beneath or above the earth’s surface) and their productive capacities in specific contexts. The current form of such natural endowments typically reflects the past and present social transformation of nature as well as natural developments that occur without human intervention. Virgin land and analogous resources are not produced as commodities by capitalist enterprises but are appropriated as gifts of nature and then transformed for profit – often without due regard to their specific reproduction cycles, overall renewability, or, in the case of land, water and air, their capacities to absorb waste and pollution. Money is a unit of account, store of value, means of payment (for example, taxes, tithes and fines), and a medium of economic exchange. Regardless of whether it has a natural form (for example, cowrie shells), a commodity form (for example, precious metals) or a fiduciary form (for example, paper notes, electronic money), the monetary system in which such monies circulate is not (and could not be) a purely economic phenomenon that is produced and operated solely for profit. For money’s ability to perform its economic functions depends critically on extra-economic institutions, sanctions and personal and impersonal trust. Insofar as money circulates as national money, the state has a key role in securing a formally rational monetary system; conversely, its increasing circulation as stateless money poses serious problems regarding the regulation of monetary relations. Knowledge is a collectively produced common resource based on individual, organizational and collective learning over different time horizons and in varied contexts – non-commercial as well as commercial. Since knowledge is not inherently scarce (in orthodox economic terms, it is a non-rival good), it only gains a commodity form insofar as it is made artificially scarce and access thereto is made to depend on payment (in the form of royalties, license fees, etc.). Thus a profound social reorganization is required to transform knowledge into something that can be sold. Finally, the ability to work is a generic human capacity. It gains a commodity form only insofar as workers can be induced or coerced to enter labor markets as waged labor. Moreover, even when it has acquired a commodity form, labor-power is reproduced through non-market as well as market institutions and social relations.
Bob Jessop, The Future of the Capitalist State (Cambridge: Polity, 2002), pp. 13-14.

top


__________________________________
Latin American Consensus

Over the course of the past seven years, Latin America has seen the rebirth of nationalist and socialist political movements. Following Hugo Chávez’s 1998 landslide victory in Venezuela, one country after another has turned left. Today, roughly 300 million of Latin America’s 520 million citizens live under governments that either want to reform the Washington Consensus – a euphemism for the mix of punishing fiscal austerity, privatization and market liberalization that has produced staggering levels of poverty and inequality over the past three decades – or abolish it altogether and create a new, more equitable global economy... Anchored by Brazil’s enormous market and advanced agricultural, pharmaceutical, heavy equipment, steel and aeronautical sectors, the countries of South America have taken a number of steps to diversify the hemisphere’s economy. They courted non-US trade and investment, particularly from Asia. Fueled by a consuming thirst for Latin America’s raw materials – its oil, ore and soybeans – the Chinese government has negotiated more than 400 investment and trade deals with Latin America over the past few years, investing more than $50 billion in the region. China is both Brazil’s and Argentina’s fourth-largest trading partner, providing $7 billion for port and railroad modernization and signing $20 billion worth of commercial agreements. South American leaders have also sought to deepen regional economic integration, primarily by expanding the Mercosur – South America’s most important commercial alliance – and embarking on an ambitious road-building project. In December [2005] Lula claimed that Brazil’s trade with the rest of Latin America grew by nearly 90 percent since the previous year, compared with a 20 percent increase with the United States... Last December Venezuela joined Argentina, Brazil, Uruguay and Paraguay as a full member in Mercosur. At the same meeting where it approved Venezuela’s petition for admission, Mercosur established a Parliament modeled on the European Union, agreeing to cooperate on a range of issues, including multilateral trade agreements with countries like China.
One sign that economic diversification is gaining force was the success in 2005 of then Argentine President Néstor Kirchner’s take-it-or-leave-it offer of 30 cents on every dollar owed on its $100 billion external debt, to be paid in long-term, low-interest bonds. In the past, financial markets would have severely punished such insolence, but with Asian investment pouring in and the economy rebounding at a steady clip, a majority of lenders had no choice but to make the deal.
Greg Grandin, “Latin America’s New Consensus,” www.thenation.com/doc/20060501/grandin.

In 2005, 80% of IMF’s $81 billion loan portfolio was to Latin America. Today, it’s 1% with nearly all its $17 billion in outstanding loans to Turkey and Pakistan. The World Bank is also being rejected. Venezuela had already paid off its IMF and World Bank debt ahead of schedule when Hugo Chavez symbolically announced on April 30: “We will no longer have to go to Washington nor to the IMF nor to the World Bank, not to anyone.” Ecuador’s Raphael Correa is following suit. He cleared his country’s IMF debt, suspended World Bank loans, accused the WB of trying to extort money from him when he was economy and finance minister in 2005, and last April declared the Bank’s country representative persona non grata in an extraordinary diplomatic slap in the face... The Banco del Sur will replace these repressive institutions with $7 billion in startup capital when it begins operating in 2008. It will be under “a new financial architecture” for regional investment with the finance ministers of each member nation sitting on the bank’s administrative council with equal authority over its operations as things now stand. Venezuelan Finance Minister Rodrigo Cabeza stressed “The idea is to rely on a development agency for us, led by us” to finance public and private development and regional integration projects. “There will not be credit subjected to economic policies. There will not be credit that produces a calamity for our people and as a result, it will not be a tool of domination” like the international lending agencies.
Stephen Lendman, “The Bank of the South,” www.zmag.org/content/showarticle.cfm?ItemID=14164.
The ALBA (Alternativa Bolivariana para las Américas) is a proposed alternative to the U.S.-sponsored Free Trade Area of the Americas (FTAA), differing from the latter in that it advocates a socially-oriented trade block rather than one strictly based on the logic of deregulated profit maximization…. One of the obstacles to confront is the deep disparity that exists in development between the countries of the hemisphere, whereby poor countries such as Haiti or Bolivia are compelled to compete with the world’s leading economic power. In order to help overcome trade disadvantages, ALBA pushes for solidarity with the economically weakest countries, with the aim of achieving a free trade area in which all of its members benefit.
Teresa Arreaza, “ALBA,” www.venezuelanalysis.com/analysis/339.

top


__________________________________
Military-Economic Bifurcation

In the century following the defeat of China in the first Opium War [1839-42], the eclipse of East Asia turned into what Ken Pomeranz has called “The Great Divergence.” The political and economic fortunes of two world regions up until then characterized by similar living standards diverged sharply, Europe rapidly ascending to the zenith of its power and East Asia just as rapidly descending to its nadir... The situation appeared to be changing in the late 1960s and early 1970s, when the mighty US military apparatus failed to coerce the Vietnamese people into a permanent scission along the Cold War divide... The economic conjuncture also seemed to favor the countries that had come to constitute the Third World. Their natural resources were in great demand, and so were their abundant and cheap labor supplies. Capital flows from First (and Second) World countries experienced a major expansion; the rapid industrialization of Third World countries was undermining the previous concentration of manufacturing activities in First (and Second) World countries; and Third World countries had united across ideological divides to demand a New International Economic Order...
In the 1980s, a US-driven escalation of competition in world financial markets had suddenly dried up the supply of funds to the Third and Second World countries and provoked a major contraction of world demand for their products. Terms of trade had swung back in favor of the First World... The Soviet empire disintegrated. Instead of having the two superpowers to play off each other, Third World countries now had to compete with the former Second World countries in gaining access to the markets and resources of the First World. At the same time, the United States and its European allies seized the opportunity created by the collapse of the USSR to claim with some success a global “monopoly” of the legitimate use of violence... Nonetheless the backlash had not re-established power relations to their pre-1970 condition. For the waning of Soviet power had been accompanied by the waxing of what Bruce Cummings dubbed the “capitalist archipelago” of East Asia... The collective economic power of the archipelago as new “workshop” and “cash box” of the world was forcing the traditional centers of capitalist power – Western Europe and North America – to restructure and reorganize their own industries, their own economies, and their own ways of life. A bifurcation of this kind between military and economic power, I argued [in the early 1990s], had no precedent in the annals of capitalist history and could develop in three quite different directions. The United States and its European allies might have attempted to use their military superiority to extract a “protection payment” from the emerging capitalist centers of East Asia. If the attempt succeeded, the first truly global empire in world history might have come into existence. If no such attempt was made, over time East Asia might have become the center of world-market society... But it was also possible that the bifurcation would result in endless worldwide chaos...
Trends and events have changed radically the probability that each of these outcomes will actually materialize. Worldwide violence has escalated further and the Bush administration’s embrace of the Project for a New American Century in response to the events of September 11, 2001 was, in key respects, an attempt to bring into existence the first truly global empire in world history. The abysmal failure of the Project on the Iraqi testing-ground has not eliminated but nonetheless greatly reduced the chances that a Western-centered global empire will ever materialize. The chances of endless worldwide chaos have probably increased. At the same time, the probability that we will witness the formation of an East-Asian-centered world-market society has also increased. The brighter prospects of this outcome are in part due to the disastrous implications for US world power of the Iraqi adventure. For the most part, however, they are due to China’s spectacular economic advance since the early 1990s.
Giovanni Arrighi, Adam Smith in Beijing: Lineages of the 21st Century (London: Verso, 2007), pp. 5-8.

top


__________________________________
Neoconservative Morality

One of the keystones of modern economic thought is that it is impossible to have an a priori knowledge of what constitutes happiness for other people; that such knowledge is incorporated in an individual’s “utility schedules”; and this knowledge, in turn, is revealed by the choices the individual makes in a free market... What we are witnessing in Western society today [with the American New Left in the 1960s] are the beginnings of a counterrevolution against this conception of man and society. It is a shamefaced counterrevolution, full of bad faith and paltry sophistry, because it feels compelled to define itself as some kind of progressive extension of modernity instead of what it so clearly is, a reactionary revulsion against modernity...
Certainly, one of the key problematic aspects of bourgeois-liberal society has long been known and announced. This is the fact that liberal society is of necessity a secular society, one in which religion is mainly a private affair... Liberal civilization finds itself having spiritually expropriated the masses of its citizenry, whose demands for material compensation gradually become as infinite as the infinity they have lost... For well over a hundred and fifty years now, social critics have been warning us that bourgeois society was living off the accumulated moral capital of traditional religion and traditional moral philosophy, and that once this capital was depleted, bourgeois society would find its legitimacy ever more questionable... It is becoming clear that religion, and a moral philosophy associated with religion, is far more important politically than the philosophy of liberal individualism admits... The enemy of liberal capitalism today is not so much socialism as nihilism...
When [the neoliberal economist] Hayek criticizes “scientism,” he does indeed write very much like a Burkean Whig, with a great emphasis on the superior wisdom inherent in tradition... But when he turns to a direct contemplation of present-day society, he too has to fall back on a faith in the ultimate benefits of “self-realization”... And what if the “self” that is “realized” under the conditions of liberal capitalism is a self that despises liberal capitalism, and uses its liberty to subvert and abolish a free society?... This is the question we now confront, as our society relentlessly breeds more and more such selves, whose private vices in no way provide benefits to a bourgeois order. Perhaps one can say that the secular, “libertarian” tradition of capitalism – as distinct from the Protestant-bourgeois tradition – simply had too limited an imagination when it came to vice... It could never really believe that self-destructive nihilism was an authentic and permanent possibility that any society had to guard against... It could demonstrate that the Marxist vision was utopian; but it could not demonstrate that the utopian vision of Fourier – the true ancestor of our New Left – was wrong.
What medicine does one prescribe for a social order that is sick because it has lost its soul? Our learned doctors, the social scientists, look askance at this kind of “imaginary” illness, which has dramatic physical symptoms but no apparent physical cause. Some, on what we conventionally call the “right,” cannot resist the temptation to conclude that the patient is actually in robust health, and that only his symptoms are sick. Others, on what we conventionally call the “left,” declare that the patient is indeed sick unto the death and assert that it is his symptoms which are the causes of his malady. Such confusion, of course, is exactly what one would expect when both patient and doctors are suffering from the same mysterious disease.
Irving Kristol, “Capitalism, Socialism, and Nihilism” (1973), in Neoconservatism, The Autobiography of an Idea (Chicago: Elephant Paperbacks, 1995), pp. 92-105.

top


__________________________________

Neoliberal Governmentality

In ordinary parlance, neoliberalism refers to the repudiation of Keynesian welfare state economics and the ascendance of the Chicago School of political economy – von Hayek, Friedman, et al. In popular usage, neoliberalism is equated with a radically free market: maximized competition and free trade achieved through economic deregulation, elimination of tariffs, and a range of monetary and social policies favorable to business and indifferent toward poverty, social deracination, cultural decimation, long term resource depletion and environmental destruction.... While these referents capture an important effect of neoliberalism, they also reduce neoliberalism to a bundle of economic policies with inadvertent political and social consequences: they eschew the political rationality that both organizes these policies and reaches beyond the market... This rationality is emerging as governmentality – a mode of governance encompassing but not limited to the state, and one which produces subjects, forms of citizenship and behavior, and a new organization of the social... One of the more incisive accounts of neo-liberal political rationality comes from Michel Foucault’s 1978 and 1979 College de France lectures, still untranscribed and unpublished. Thanks to German sociologist Thomas Lemke, we have an excellent summary and interpretation of Foucault’s lectures on neoliberalism.
The political sphere, along with every other dimension of contemporary existence, is submitted to an economic rationality, or put the other way around, not only is the human being configured exhaustively as homo oeconomicus, all dimensions of human life are cast in terms of a market rationality. While this entails submitting every action and policy to considerations of profitability, equally important is the production of all human and institutional action as rational entrepreneurial action, conducted according to a calculus of utility, benefit, or satisfaction against a micro-economic grid of scarcity, supply and demand, and moral value-neutrality. Neoliberalism does not simply assume that all aspects of social, cultural and political life can be reduced to such a calculus, rather it develops institutional practices and rewards for enacting this vision. That is, through discourse and policy promulgating its criteria, neoliberalism produces rational actors and imposes market rationale for decision-making in all spheres...
Liberal democracy cannot be submitted to neoliberal political governmentality and survive. There is nothing in liberal democracy's basic institutions or values – from free elections, representative democracy, and individual liberties equally distributed, to modest power-sharing or even more substantive political participation – that inherently meets the test of serving economic competitiveness or inherently withstands a cost-benefit analysis. And it is liberal democracy that is going under in the present moment, even as the flag of American “democracy” is being planted everywhere it finds or creates soft ground.
Wendy Brown, “Neoliberalism and the End of Liberal Democracy,” Theory & Event 7/1, 2003.

top


__________________________________

Non-State Public Sphere

In “Results of the Immediate Process of Production,” Marx analyzes intellectual labor and distinguishes two principal kinds. On the one hand, there is the immaterial activity that has as its result “commodities which exist separately from the producer..., e.g. books, paintings and all products of art as distinct from the artistic achievement of the practising artist.” On the other hand, Marx defines those activities in which “the product is not separable from the act of producing” – in other words, activities that find their fulfillment in themselves, without being objectivized in a finished work existing outside and beyond them. The second kind of intellectual labor may be exemplified by “performing artists,” such as pianists or dancers, but also includes more generally various kinds of people whose work involves a virtuoso performance, such as orators, teachers, doctors, and priests. In short, this second kind of intellectual labor refers to a wide cross section of human society, ranging from Glenn Gould to the impeccable butler of the classic English novel.
The activities in which “the product is not separable from the act of producing” have a mercurial and ambiguous status that is not always and not completely grasped by the critique of political economy. The reason for the difficulty is simple. Well before becoming swallowed up within capitalist production, virtuosity was the architrave of ethics and politics. Furthermore, it was what qualified Action, as distinct from (and in fact opposed to) Work. Aristotle writes that the aim of production is different from production itself, whereas the aim of action could not be, inasmuch as virtuous conduct is an end in itself.
Within post-Fordist organization of production, activity-without-a-finished-work moves from being a special and problematic case to becoming the prototype of waged labor in general. When labor carries out tasks of overseeing and coordination, in other words when it “steps to the side of the production process instead of being its chief actor,” its function consists no longer in the carrying out of a single particular objective, but in the modulation (as well as the variation and intensification) of social cooperation, in other words, that ensemble of relations and systemic connections that as of now are “the great foundation-stone of production and of wealth.” This modulation takes place through linguistic services that, far from giving rise to a final product, exhaust themselves in the communicative interaction that their own “performance” brings about.
Post-Fordist activity presupposes and, at the same time, unceasingly re-creates the “public realm” (the space of cooperation, precisely) that Arendt describes as the indispensable prerequisite of both the dancer and the politician. The “presence of others” is both the instrument and the object of labor; therefore, the processes of production always require a certain degree of virtuosity, or, to put it another way, they involve what are really political actions. Mass intellectuality is called upon to exercise the art of the possible, to deal with the unforeseen, to profit from opportunities. Now that the slogan of labor that produces surplus value has become, sarcastically, “politics first,” politics in the narrow sense of the term becomes discredited or paralyzed.
The key to political action (or rather the only possibility of extracting it from its present state of paralysis) consists in developing the publicness of Intellect outside of Work, and in opposition to it. The issue here has two distinct profiles, which are, however, strictly complementary. On the one hand, general intellect can only affirm itself as an autonomous public sphere, thus avoiding the “transfer” of its own potential into the absolute power of Administration, if it cuts the linkage that binds it to the production of commodities and wage labor. On the other hand, the subversion of capitalist relations of production henceforth develops only with the institution of a non-State public sphere, a political community that has as its hinge general intellect. The salient characteristics of the post-Fordist experience (servile virtuosity, the valorization even of the faculty of language, the necessary relation with the “presence of others,” and so forth) postulate as a conflictual response nothing less than a radically new form of democracy.
Paolo Virno, “Virtuosity and Revolution: The Political Theory of Exodus,” in Radical Thought in Italy (Minneapolis: U. of Minnesota Press, 1996); http://www.16beavergroup.org/mtarchive/archives/000941.php.

top


__________________________________

Overaccumulation Crisis

Overaccumulation within a given territorial system means a condition of surpluses of labor (rising unemployment) and surpluses of capital (registered as a glut of commodities on the market that cannot be disposed of without a loss, as idle productive capacity and/or as surpluses of money capital lacking outlets for productive and profitable investment). Such surpluses can be potentially absorbed by (a) temporal displacement through investment in long-term capital projects or social expenditures (such as education and research) that defer the reentry of capital values into circulation into the future, (b) spatial displacements through opening up new markets, new production capacities and new resource, social and labor possibilities elsewhere, or (c) some combination of (a) and (b).
The general picture which then emerges, is of a networked spatio-temporal world of financial flows of surplus capital with conglomerations of political and economic power at key nodal points (New York, London, Tokyo) seeking either to disburse and absorb the surpluses down productive paths, more often than not in long-term projects across a variety of spaces (from Bangladesh to Brazil or China), or to use speculative power to rid the system of overaccumulation by the visitation of crises of devaluation upon vulnerable territories. It is of course the populations of those vulnerable territories who then must pay the inevitable price, in terms of loss of assets, loss of jobs, and loss of economic security, to say nothing of the loss of dignity and hope. Capitalism survives, therefore, not only through a series of spatio-temporal fixes that absorb the capital surpluses in productive and constructive ways, but also through the devaluation and destruction administered as corrective medicine to what is generally depicted as the fiscal profligacy of those who borrow. The very idea that those who irresponsibly lend might also be held responsible is, of course, dismissed out of hand by ruling elites.
In the current conjuncture, an obvious candidate to absorb surplus capital is China. Net foreign direct investment rose from $5 billion in 1991 to around $50 billion in 2002. Since 1998, the Chinese have sought to absorb their vast labor surpluses (and to curb the threat of social unrest) by debt-financed investment in huge mega-projects that dwarf the already huge Three Gorges dam. This effort is far larger in toto than that which the United States undertook during the 1950s and 1960s, and has the potential to absorb surpluses of capital for several years to come. It is, however, deficit-financed, and that entails huge risks since if the investments do not return their value to the accumulation process in due course, then a fiscal crisis of the state will quickly engulf China with serious consequences for economic development and social stability. Nevertheless, this proposes to be a remarkable version of a spatio-temporal fix that has global implications not only for absorbing overaccumulated capital, but also for shifting the balance of economic and political power to China as the regional hegemon and perhaps placing the Asian region, under Chinese leadership, in a much more competitive position vis-à-vis the United States.
A second possible outcome, however, is increasingly fierce international competition as multiple dynamic centers of capital accumulation compete on the world stage in the face of strong currents of overaccumulation. Since they cannot all succeed in the long run, either the weakest succumb and fall into serious crises of localized devaluation or geopolitical struggles arise between regions. The latter can get converted via the territorial logic of power into confrontations between states in the form of trade wars and currency wars, with the ever-present danger of military confrontations (of the sort that gave us two world wars in the twentieth century).
David Harvey, The New Imperialism (Oxford UP, 2003/2005), pp. 109, 134-35, 123-24.

top


__________________________________

Risk Society

The idea that the dynamism of industrial society undercuts its own foundations recalls the message of Karl Marx that capitalism is its own gravedigger, but it means something quite different. First, it is not the crises, but the victories of capitalism which produce the new social form. This means, second, that it is not the class struggle but rather normal modernization and further modernization which are dissolving the contours of industrial society... On the one hand, society still makes decisions and takes action according to the pattern of the old industrial society, but, on the other, the interest organizations, the judicial system and politics are clouded over by debates and conflicts that stem from the dynamism of risk society...
With the advent of risk society, the distributional conflicts over “goods” (income, jobs, social security), which constituted the basic conflict of classical industrial society and led to attempted solutions in the relevant institutions, are covered over by the distributional conflicts over “bads”... They erupt over how the risks accompanying goods production (nuclear and chemical mega-technology, genetic research, the threat to the environment, over-militarization and the increasing immiseration outside Western industrial society) can be distributed, prevented, controlled and legitimized... In the risk society, the recognition of the unpredictability of the threats provoked by techno-industrial development necessitates self-reflection on the foundations of social cohesion and the examination of prevailing conventions and foundations of “rationality”... In other words, risk society is by tendency also a self-critical society... Experts are undercut or deposed by opposing experts. Politicians encounter the resistance of citizens’ groups, and industrial management encounters morally and politically motivated organized consumer boycotts... Uncertainty returns and proliferates everywhere. Non-Marxist critique of modernization, small and concrete, but large and fundamental as well, is becoming an everyday phenomenon... Lines of conflict are coming into being over the what and how of progress, and they are becoming capable of organization and of building coalitions...
The socially most astonishing and surprising – and perhaps the least understood – phenomenon of the 1980s was the unexpected renaissance of a political subjectivity, outside and inside the institutions. In this sense, it is no exaggeration to say that citizen-initiative groups have taken power politically. They were the ones that put the issue of an [ecologically] endangered world on the agenda, against the resistance of the established parties... The themes of the future, which are now on everyone’s lips, have not originated from the farsightedness of the rulers or from the struggle in parliament – and certainly not from the cathedrals of power in business, science and the state. They have been put on the social agenda against the concerted resistance of its institutionalized ignorance by entangled, moralizing groups fighting each other over the proper way, split and plagued by doubts... This applies not only to the West, but also to the East of Europe. There the citizens’ groups – contrary to the entire social science intelligentsia – started from zero and with no organization, in a system of surveilled conformity, and yet, with no copying machines or telephones, were able to force the ruling group to retreat and collapse just by assembling in a square... In society without consensus, devoid of a legitimating core, it is evident that even a single gust of wind, caused by the cry for freedom, can bring down the whole house of cards of power.
Ulrich Beck, “The Reinvention of Politics,” in U. Beck, A. Giddens, S. Lash, Reflexive Modernization (Standford U.P., 1994), pp. 1-55.

top



_________________________________
_
Subjective Cartography

The subject is not self-evident; it’s not sufficient to think in order to be, as Descartes declared, since all sorts of other ways of existing establish themselves outside consciousness, and whenever thought deliberately tries to grasp itself it’s likely to take off like a madly spinning top, without any hold on the real territories of existence that drift off from each other in all directions like tectonic plates beneath the surface of the continents. Rather than the subject, maybe we should speak of components of subjectivation, each working more or less on its own. This would necessarily lead us to re-examine the relation between the individual and subjectivity, and above all, to make a clear distinction between the two concepts. The vectors of subjectivation do not necessarily run through the individual, who in reality appears more in the position of a “terminal” for processes involving human groups, socioeconomic complexes, informational machines, etc. Thus, interiority comes into being at the crossroads of multiple components, each relatively autonomous, and in some cases, positively discordant with respect to the others.
It remains very difficult to make such arguments heard... It’s as though a scientific super-ego demanded that psychic entities be reified, and insisted that they only be approached through extrinsic coordinates... I find it urgent to rid ourselves of scientistic references and metaphors in order to forge new paradigms of ethical-aesthetic inspiration. Besides, haven’t the best cartographies of the psyche, or if you prefer, the best psychoanalysis, been carried out by Goethe, Proust, Joyce, Artaud and Beckett, rather than Freud, Jung and Lacan?... I’ve come to regard the apprehension of a psychic reality as inseparable from the articulation of speech that gives it body, both as a fact and as an expressive process... The precondition for any revival of analysis – through schizoanalysis, for example – is that as a general rule, once one takes the trouble to work with them, both individual and collective articulations of subjectivity are potentially able to develop and proliferate beyond their ordinary equilibrium. By their very nature, their analytic cartographies overflow the existential territories to which they are assigned. Thus these cartographies should be like painting and literature, domains where each concrete performance is destined to evolve, to innovate, to inaugurate prospective openings, without their authors being able to base themselves on secure theoretical foundations or the authority of a group, a school, a conservatory or an academy...
Social ecology should work on the reconstruction of human relations at all the levels of the socius. It should never lose sight of the fact that capitalist power has delocalized, deterritorialized, at once extensively, by extending its empire across the entirety of the social, economic and cultural life of the planet, and intensively, by infiltrating the most unconscious subjective strata. Thus one can no longer claim to oppose it solely from the outside, through trade unions and traditional politics. It’s equally imperative to confront its effects in the domain of mental ecology in everyday life: individual, domestic, conjugal, neighborly, creative or personal ethics. Rather than seeking a dull and infantilizing consensus, it’s a matter of cultivating dissensus and the singular production of existence.
Félix Guattari, Les trois écologies (Paris: Galilée, 1989), pp. 22-44.

top


__________________________________

Unintended Social Order

[For Sartre], “the basic type of sociality” is the collective, the “inert gathering with its structure of seriality,” which he equates with Hegel’s “atomized crowd.” His most famous example is the bus queue where, despite having the appearance of a social group, everyone is isolated from everyone else and linked only through their alienation, which is what constitutes them in their mutual isolation... Sartre emphasizes that an inert gathering like this can be transformed in an instant, “by the flash of a common praxis,” when it recognizes its common interest. The origin of this “totalization,” as Sartre calls it, is “individual freedom conceived as the will of all.” Individuals fleeing from a common enemy realize that “it is neither Others, nor a few individuals, who flee: instead, flight, conceived as a common praxis reacting to a common threat, becomes flight as an active totality”... Sartre explicitly equates the process with the communist vision of “the gradual withering-away of the State”... Translated into the language of complexity theory, this is an example of a “dissipative structure” – a form of order that unexpectedly emerges as disorder increases. Were the equivalent to happen in the entropy of the state, the resulting dissipative structures would appear as unintended forms of social order...
Reading analyses of the post-1989 global order in light of the early twentieth-century literature on the demise of the state reveals the former to be global variations on the themes of the latter. The convergence of these theories suggests that the master narrative of contemporary geopolitics is not, as some imagine, the move towards global sovereignty or the progress of global civil society as a step toward it. Rather it is the development of global society in place of universal coercion: the reabsorption of a global state by civil society. The obvious contemporary focus for the process is the decline of American hegemony, still in its relatively early stages. But it is possible to see this as the final part of a longer, more complex process, a single transition of world historical importance: a global decolonization, its constituent phases so geographically various, and its political ideologies so distinct as to disguise the underlying continuity. That narrative is the decline of Western dominance from its peak in the early twentieth century. It has three distinct phases: the end of European empires, the fall of the Soviet Union and the waning of American hegemony. Each empire sought legitimacy in the demise of its predecessor, emphasizing the differences between them and concealing the extent to which all were aspects of the same thing – the three-headed monster of Western imperialism, a global state in all but name...
For the centenarians of Eastern Europe, the Middle East, many countries in Africa, perhaps India, and certainly Afghanistan, this will be a very recognizable history. In each case the failure has been a failure of [imperial] will, the transition often surprisingly peaceful (though none so gracious as the dissolution of the Soviet bloc) and the result a diffusion of sovereignty, partly inherited by successor states, partly dispersed, and partly reconfigured within new non- or interstate social networks.
The constituent elements in the emerging global civil society might include civilizations, intergovernmental networks, ngos, churches, international corporations, academic networks, drug cartels, al-Qaeda. These are diverse groups, but this analysis permits a taxonomy more nuanced than most, for it is able to differentiate those elements of civil society produced by the withering away of the global state from those produced by the global market, dissipative structures from products of the arbitrary will...
Rather than being the building blocks of global politics, civilizations are perhaps the dissipative structures of the entropic global state... The European Union, often implicitly viewed in terms of the Hegelian dialectic as a civil society gradually creating the unity that will allow it to be willed into statehood, may also prove to be a dissipative structure of the entropy of the global state, its growing importance an unintended consequence of the decline of first colonial, then Soviet and now American power.
If so, its relations with the United States may become increasingly conflictual. Another corollary of this analysis is that the seemingly quixotic “war against terror” is in fact just as central to the contemporary world as its advocates claim. Any “war against terror” is by definition not a war between states, but a war of the state against civil society. But this is not a war against the pre-existing structures of civil society that underlie the global state. The “long war” is being fought by the global state against the dissipative structures generated by its own entropy.
Malcom Bull, “States of Failure” (2006), New Left Review 46, pp. 16-24.

top


__________________________________

Zombie Category

What we are dealing with here is a meta-change, a change in the coordinates of change. This meta-change is best understood as a new dynamic that was created when the process of modernization began to transform its own taken-for-granted foundations. Modernity then passed an inflection point and began to change into something qualitatively new... It means all the big questions have to be rolled out again, and the small ones too. They all have to be posed anew, negotiated, and answered again – and not through universalistic arm-chair theory, but through truly transnational and comparative statistics that we have yet to develop...
My central contention is that sociology developed in the container of the nation-state. Its categories of perception, its self-understanding, and its central concepts were all molded to its contours. And because the concepts thus engendered refuse to die, the sociological imagination is now inhabited by zombie categories. They haunt our thinking. They focus our attention on realities that are steadily disappearing. And they haunt our empirical work, because even the subtlest empirical work, when framed in zombie categories, becomes blind empiricism. Zombie categories embody nineteenth-century horizons of experience, the horizons of the first modernity. And because these inappropriate horizons, distilled into a priori and analytic categories, still mold our perceptions, they are blinding us to the real experience and the ambiguities of the second modernity...
The achievement of classical sociology was to grasp the internal dynamics of the industrial market society that was then just coming into existence. Sociologists distilled its basic principles out of their own contemporary experience. The concepts they developed spread out and conquered the intellectual world. They were extremely fruitful for empirical research and they had huge political effects. But the irony is that the power of these ideas, and their consequent success, was all founded on this questionable inference from each theorist’s society to the society in general. We could call it the universalist inference. It's false. Yet the perspective it made possible had an enormous amount of explanatory power...
What we need to do now is to make the change from a universal perspective to a cosmopolitan perspective. When we infer from a society, usually our own society, to society in general, the result is a naive universalism. Globality, by contrast, is what results when sociologists from all countries of the world, having interpreted their own societies through the use of the same universal categories, then meet and confront each other with their different findings and try to reconcile them. It then becomes immediately clear that there is no longer a privileged standpoint from which society can be investigated. In order to deal with this problem, a global or cosmopolitan society has to introduce a radical change of view. It has to open itself up to a dialogic imagination and research... It has to get away from the North Atlantic, and from the myth that this region shows the rest of the world its future. It has to move out to embrace the social cosmos.
Ulrich Beck, Johannes Willms, Conversations with Ulrich Beck (Cambridge: Polity, 2004), pp. 16-19.

return to top


*ground as the contradiction and tragic failure of capitalism right now:
--ground rent, for everything that concerns housing
--ground to the bone, for flexible labor
--ground as the earth itself, overheating and poisoned
--ground zero wherever a bomb goes off and people die